* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Lecture 7. Classical monetary theory
Fiscal multiplier wikipedia , lookup
Economic bubble wikipedia , lookup
Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup
Virtual economy wikipedia , lookup
Nominal rigidity wikipedia , lookup
Real bills doctrine wikipedia , lookup
Business cycle wikipedia , lookup
Modern Monetary Theory wikipedia , lookup
International monetary systems wikipedia , lookup
Economic calculation problem wikipedia , lookup
Monetary policy wikipedia , lookup
Long Depression wikipedia , lookup
Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup
Helicopter money wikipedia , lookup
Austrian business cycle theory wikipedia , lookup
EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory Almaty, KZ :: 23 October 2015 EC3115 Monetary Economics Lecture 7: Classical monetary theory Anuar D. Ushbayev International School of Economics Kazakh-British Technical University https://anuarushbayev.wordpress.com/teaching/ec3115-2015/ Tengri Partners | Merchant Banking & Private Equity a.ushbayev@tengripartners.com – www.tengripartners.com Almaty, Kazakhstan, 23 October 2015 ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 2 / 38 - Relevant reading Book treatment F. Mishkin. (2013). The Economics of Money, Banking and Financial Markets, 10th edition, Pearson Education, Chapter 20. J. Handa. (2009). Monetary Economics, 2nd edition, Chapter 18. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 3 / 38 - The quantity theory of money Section 1 The quantity theory of money ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 4 / 38 - The quantity theory of money “[The quantity theory of money] is fundamental. Its correspondence with fact is not open to question. Nevertheless it is often misstated and misrepresented.” – John Maynard Keynes, (1924), Tract on Monetary Reform. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 5 / 38 - The quantity theory of money History of the QTM Initially developed by, among others, John Stuart Mill, who expanded on the ideas of David Hume. The more relevant mathematical formulation was later given by the American economist Irving Fisher in 19111 . The idea goes that in a monetary economy in which non-monetary transactions are insignificant, one may write: M · Vtransactions = pT q |{z} P = i ( pi ·qi ) where M is the average total amount of money in circulation over a period, Vtransactions is the transactions velocity of money, and p and q are vectors of prices and quantities of all transactions. 1 I. Fisher. (1911). The Purchasing Power of Money. Its Determination and Relation to Credit, Interest and Crises. New York: Macmillan. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 6 / 38 - The quantity theory of money In a simplification, the above reduces to what is called the equation of exchange: M · Vtransactions = Ptransactions · T where now Ptransactions is the price level over a period and T is the index of the real value of all transactions. With the development of national income and product accounts this has been refomulated: M ·V = P·Y where V is the velocity of money in final expenditures and Y is an index of real value of final expenditures. The equation of exchange thus states that the quantity of money multiplied by the number of times that this money is spent in a given year must equal nominal income (the total nominal amount spent on goods and services in that year). ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 7 / 38 - The quantity theory of money The Cambridge approach From Alfred Marshall and Arthur Pigou, Keynes had inherited an alternative version of the above statement of relationship between goods, prices and money, which focused more on money demand, rather than supply: Md = k · P · Y The Cambridge economists argued that a certain portion of the money supply will not be used for transactions and will be held in cash balances instead. This cash portion of nominal income is denoted k in the above Cambridge cash balances equation. When the economy is at equilibrium (M d = M ), and assuming that in the short-run both Y and k are fixed, we see that the above can be rearranged to give where ISE – KBTU 1 k 1 = P·Y k is equivalent to V from the equation of exchange. M· A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 8 / 38 - The quantity theory of money The quantity theory of money Now the above formulaic results can begin to be used for theorizing about the price level dynamics. Rearranging the equation of exchange and adding a subscript for the time variable we get: Pt = M t · Vt Yt Log-linearization: ln Pt = ln M t + ln Vt − ln Yt Differentiating w.r.t. time: 1 · dPt = 1 Pt dt Mt or, in growth rates notation: · dM t dt + 1 Vt · dVt dt − 1 Yt · dYt dt %∆Pt = %∆M t + %∆Vt − %∆Yt ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 9 / 38 - The quantity theory of money Further, assuming short-run exogeneity of both velocity and real output, we get: :−0%∆Y :0 %∆Pt = %∆M t + %∆V t t Which is equivalent to saying: %∆Pt = %∆M t | {z } | {z } π m i.e. the growth rate of the price level – the inflation rate – is equal to the rate of growth of the money supply. If, on the other hand you assume only the stability of the velocity of money, the growth rate relation becomes: %∆Pt = %∆M t − %∆Yt | {z } π i.e. the inflation rate is equal to the rate of growth of the money supply minus the rate of growth of real output. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 10 / 38 - The quantity theory of money H0 : π = %∆M – No support from the data at annual frequency ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 11 / 38 - The quantity theory of money H1 : π = %∆M − %∆Y – ditto. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 12 / 38 - The quantity theory of money Since... velocity is not constant either ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 13 / 38 - The quantity theory of money ...but is positively related to the interest rate ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 14 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis Section 2 The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 15 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis The classical view Real variables – measured in physical units: quantities and relative prices, e.g.: real output: quantity of output produced real wage: output earned per hour of work real interest rate: output earned in the future by lending one unit of output today Nominal variables – measured in monetary units, e.g.: nominal wage: units of money earned per hour of work nominal interest rate: units of money earned in future by lending one unit of money today the price level: the amount of money units needed to buy a representative basket of goods ⇒ ∆ in the price level is merely a ∆ in the units of measurement. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 16 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis Classical dichotomy: in the classical model nominal and real variables are separable and therefore nominal variables do not affect real variables. Neutrality of money: changes in the the stock of money do not affect real variables. Wages and prices are completely flexible. Only real variables (preferences, factor supply, technology) determine real outcomes (quantities of output and relative prices). Monetary variables determine only monetary outcomes (value of output and absolute prices), from the equation of exchange. Demand and supply functions for goods are therefore notional and possess homogeneity of degree zero in all prices. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 17 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis Say’s law Attributed to Jean-Baptiste Say in the first quarter of the 19th century, considered to be one of the underpinnings of the classical (pre-Keynesian) macroeconomic model. Usual statement: “Supply creates its own demand”. Original idea considered a pure exchange economy (and thus was meant to refer exclusively to commodities) with N goods. More precise statement: “Aggregate supply of commodities creates its own aggregate demand”. Formally (since Say was not explicit on the role of prices) expressed as: N N X X pi Di ≡ pi Si i=1 i=1 i.e. there is no excess demand for any and all commodities irrespective of the price level: N N X X pi EiD ≡ 0 pi Di − Si ≡ i=1 ISE – KBTU i=1 A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 18 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis Original logic of causation from supply to demand: the supply of commodities creates income which the recipients must spend on commodities, so that any increase in the aggregate supply of commodities creates a corresponding increase in the aggregate demand for them. Obviously falls apart once financial assets are allowed to exist: increase in income could be partly or wholly used to increase money balances or e.g. bond holdings, so that the increase in the aggregate supply of commodities would cause a less than equal increase in their aggregate demand. conversely, an increase in commodity demand can be induced by running down money or bond holdings, so that the increase in the aggregate demand for commodities will come about without a corresponding prior increase in their supply. ⇒ Hence, the causal argument behind Say’s law is invalid in modern monetary economies. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 19 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis Original logic of identity of supply and demand for all goods: “A product is no sooner created, than it, from that instant, affords a market for other products to the full extent of its own value.”2 Failures of validity are rather obvious: Say’s law asserts that the aggregate demand for commodities always equals their aggregate supply, irrespective of the price level – i.e. money is neutral in the short-run – which is contrary to all modern econometric studies, economic intuition and modeling. If Say’s law is correct generally, then it should also be true for the labour market – i.e. widespread involuntary unemployment (caused by inadequate demand) cannot occur – which is markedly untrue in recessions. Say’s central notion concerning money was that if one has money, it is irrational to hoard it – i.e. there is no precautionary, speculative or finance motive to hold money – which is markedly untrue given the rise of the role of financial assets in modernity. 2 J.-B. Say. (1834 [1803]). A Treatise on Political Economy. [English translation]. Philadelphia: Grigg & Elliott. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 20 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis Walras’ law Due to Leon Walras, fundamental to macroeconomic analysis, underlies IS-LM. Considers at first a monetary exchange economy with N + 1 goods, the extra good being money.: for any economy, over any given period of time, the sum of the market values of all the goods demanded must equal the sum of the market values of all the goods supplied. Expressed mathematically as: N +1 N +1 X X pi Si pi Di ≡ i=1 i=1 i.e. the sum of nominal demands for all goods identically equals the sum of the nominal supplies of all goods: N +1 +1 X NX pi Di − Si ≡ pi EiD ≡ 0 i=1 ISE – KBTU i=1 A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 21 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis Implication of above: p j E jD = − N +1 X pi EiD i=1,i6= j This means that if EiD = 0 ∀ i = 1, ..., N then END+1 = 0 i.e. if there exists equilibrium in N markets, then there would also be equilibrium in the (N + 1)th market. In the absence of financial assets, Say’s law can be reformulated in the Walrasian setting to be: “If and only if the excess demand for money is zero, then Walras’ law implies Say’s law for other goods”: D Emoney + N X pi EiD = 0 i=1 ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 22 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis The demand for good i will depend on the relative prices and also on income. 1 pN PN +1 p1 Di = f i , ..., , ,Y pN +1 pN +1 PN +1 Using money as the numeraire good, its price in terms of itself is 1, of course. And hence, without so far giving more structure to the functional form of the supply function for good i, the excess demand for good i will take the form: p1 pN E Di = f i , ..., , Y − Si pN +1 pN +1 Demand curves are functions of relative prices and are homogeneous of degree zero in all relative prices. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 23 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis Demand functions here are based on the axiom of substitutability of commodities – which gives rise to relative prices Money and commodities are not substitutable in this sense and thus money can have no effect on the quantities demanded for commodity goods. Monetary prices are arbitrary scale-transformations of the relative prices, deriving from the arbitrary monetary value assigned to the real numeraire. On this basis, money is “neutral” in the determination of equilibrium prices and constitutes a mere “veil” that can simply be ignored in determining the equilibrium level of production and employment. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 24 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis Note that in this world money has no store of value function, but is simply a medium of exchange a currency of the Marshallian type, serving no other purpose than to make the exchange process fluid, and the demand for it is thus exclusively transactions-driven. We have, however, already seen that Keynesian analysis has subsequently shown that the demand for money in reality has more components, than pure transactions-driven demand. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 25 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis Pigou and real balance effects All of the above was so far cautioned with the words “in equilibrium”. When critiqued, classical economists maintained that, while disequilibrium obviously exists, any such state of disequilibrium will incorporate certain “market forces” that will bring the economy back into equilibirum. Among such forces were the two classical attempts to relax the dichotomy while retaining the neutrality of money: Pigou effect ∂ real consumption | ∂ financial {z assets } + × ∂ financial assets | ∂{zP − <0 } A disequilibrium with deficient demand for commodities will cause a fall in their prices. Since wealth includes financial assets, the fall in price level will increase wealth, which, in turn, will increase consumption and aggregate demand, bringing the economy back to equilibrium. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 26 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis Patinkin’s real balance effect ∂ real consumption | ∂ (M /P) {z + } × ∂ (M /P) | ∂{zP } <0 − A price level fall due to a demand deficiency will increase the real value of money holdings and thereby increase the household’s wealth. This will lead to an increase in consumption and therefore in aggregate demand, bringing the economy back to equilibrium. Neither effect is significant empirically. Pigou himself had later described the Pigou effect as a mere toy, based on extremely improbably assumptions. Rather, in reality, he said, the deflationary fall in prices would be accompanied by bankruptcies among firms and a fall in the physical capital stock in production. This would cause a decrease in real wealth, a rise in unemployment and a fall in aggregate demand. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 27 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis More specific groupings Since in equilibrium Walras’ law holds for all markets, then it does not matter how we group the markets. E.g. we can have a 4-good economy consisting of the markets for commodities (c), money (m), bonds and equities (b), and labour (n). EcD + EmD + E bD + EnD ≡ 0 Note that a useful feature of the Walras’ law is that market clearing for the (N+1)th market is guaranteed once the other N markets clear. This means that in general equilibrium analysis, we can exclude explicit treatment of one chosen market. It of course continues to exist and to function but its treatment becomes implicit. Solutions and equilibrium values of real variables and prices will be identical irrespective of which market is omitted from the explicit analysis. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 28 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis One of the major points of debate between the classical and the Keynesian schools concerns the issue of whether the labor markets will or will not clear over a reasonably short period (nevermind continuously) – at the same time not clearing continuously in the commodities, money and financial markets. i.e. whether the following is true: Dn = Sn ∗ n=n (full employment) =⇒ EcD + EmD + E bD ≡ 0 In fact, however, in economies with developed financial markets, the most plausible assumption would be that the money and bonds markets adjust the fastest to clear any disequilibrium. At the same time, the labor markets are the slowest to adjust since they are characterized by long-term contracts. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 29 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis While Walras’ law holds in the general equilibrium states of the economy, its implications for the dynamic analysis of prices, wages and interest rates (i.e. in disequilibrium) are not always valid. E.g. let’s consider the following. The money and bond markets are so efficient in the modern financially developed economies that they adjust continuously while the financial markets are open – i.e. they can be regarded as continuously in equilibrium for analytical purposes. EmD = E bD = 0 This means that EcD = −EnD Hence, the must be a positive excess demand for commodities whenever there is excess supply of labour. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 30 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis However, the real experience of economic recessions show that they are usually described by the combination: EnD < 0 – positive unemployment (i.e. negative excess demand for labour), and EcD < 0 – shortage of demand for products of businesses. That is excess supply for labour and excess supply of commodities occur simultaneously in recessions. Similarly, during an economic boom (positive demand shock): EcD > 0 – an excess demand for commodities can trigger EnD > 0 – an response from businesses in the form of increased output and employment. This casts doubt either on the validity of Walras’ law itself in disequilibrium or on the validity of the assumptions of continuous equilibrium in money and financial markets (EmD = E bD = 0). ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 31 / 38 - The classical dichotomy and Walrasian analysis What does this have to do with (monetary) policy? In disequilibrium, where the Walras’ law is violated, a shock that produces an aggregate demand deficiency of goods can be (and usually is) accompanied by an excess supply (unemployment) of labor. The free market mechanisms that should supposedly bring the economy back to equilibrium are of questionable validity, and, even if they were to be functional, would take a (really) long time. The Keynesian (and logical humanitarian) argument is that such demand-deficient situations should prompt a response from the government and the central bank. In fact, such responses to demand deficiency are, for example, embodied in the Taylor-type rules of monetary policy formulation. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 32 / 38 - A simple general equilibrium model Section 3 A simple general equilibrium model ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 33 / 38 - A simple general equilibrium model Fiat money cannot be valued by market participants in a Walrasian setting, because here the value of something that is intrinsically worthless is also zero – the imaginary Walrasian auctioneer is “too efficient” to permit an equilibrium where fiat money has non-zero value. Thus, when incorporating money in general equilibrium, an ad hoc assumption is traditionally made such that an individual agent’s utility depends on the level of real money balances. A justification, due to Don Patinkin, is that even if households plan to balance their budgets so that planned purchases are equal in value to planned sales, it may be convenient to buy and sell goods at different times. The more money they hold, the greater the extent to which they can purchase goods ahead of making sales. Money holdings stand as a proxy for the more convenient sequence of transactions they make possible. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 34 / 38 - A simple general equilibrium model Assume a household’s utility depends on the quantity of goods consumed, X , and on real money balances, M /P. Denote the household’s initial endowments of goods by X 0 and of nominal money balances by M0 . The budget constraint faced by the household in nominal terms then can be written: P X + M ≤ P X 0 + M0 i.e. the household can only afford to buy goods and accumulate nominal money balances to the value of his initial endowments of goods and money. Dividing both sides of this budget constraint by the price level gives the budget constraint in real terms: X+ ISE – KBTU M P ≤ X0 + M0 P A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 35 / 38 - A simple general equilibrium model Further assume a standard quasi concave Cobb-Douglas form of the utility function: 1 M 2 1 U=X2 P In order to maximize this utility we write down the Lagrangian: L=X 1 2 M P 1 2 + λ X0 + M0 P −X − M P and thus the first order conditions are: 1 1 − 12 M 2 dL X −λ=0 = dX 2 P 1 − 1 dLM = 12 X 2 MP 2 − λ = 0 d ISE – KBTU P A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 36 / 38 - A simple general equilibrium model Rearranging both sides for λ and equating gives: 1 1 −2 1 1 1 − 12 M 2 X X 2 MP = 2 P 2 1 X−2 1 M P 2 1 =X2 − 1 M P 2 which is solved by: X= M P Plugging this back into the budget constraint produces the optimal solution: ( M X M ISE – KBTU = = X0+ 0 P 2 P X 0 +M0 2 A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 37 / 38 - A simple general equilibrium model If we now assume that the economy is populated by nidentical households we can write the market clearing condition (by equating total demand to total supply) for the goods market as: ! M X 0 + P0 n = nX 0 2 Solving for the price level gives: P= M0 X0 Note, that we could have alternative first written the market clearing condition for the money market as: P X 0 + M0 n = nM0 2 and solving for the price level would also give: M0 P= X0 which is consistent with Walras’ law. ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015) EC3115 :: L.7 : Classical monetary theory - 38 / 38 - A simple general equilibrium model We observe that in this economy, money is neutral. Real output per household is fixed at X 0 as it depends on endowments. From the solution of the price level, a change in the money supply will only lead to a proportional increase in prices. Real money balances and production of goods do not change. An increase in money, M0 , will shift the demand function for good X outwards, but this simply causes the price level to increase: ISE – KBTU A.D. Ushbayev (2015)